Engaging today's political economy
with truth and reason

sponsored by

Weekly Sage #12: Frank Knight – Chicago School

25 Jan 2019

The Weekly Sage hopes to regularly bring brief profiles of key contributors to thought and faith before a Christian audience for historical education and awareness of valuable resources.

 

Sometimes history brings together a special combination of resources and people that form a center of intellectual influence. The Weekly Sage will occasionally consider such “Schools” together. As such this is the second of a five-week series on Chicago-School Economists. This will be understood simply to mean uniquely impactful members of the faculty of economics at the University of Chicago in the 20th century.

 

Frank Knight

Frank Knight (1885-1972) was a leading American economist and scholar of the 20th century. He left a lasting legacy on the field of economic thought through his writing and work building and overseeing the associated programs at the University of Chicago. While Knight himself never won the Nobel Prize in Economic Science, several of his students, such as Milton Friedman, George Stigler, and James Buchanan, did win the prestigious award, reflecting both Knight’s skill as an educator and the value of his ideas.

While the lake-side metropolis was the center of Knight’s influential career, he was born and raised in the rural Illinois countryside of McLean County. While his parents imparted a Christian influence on Knight’s youth, he eventually moved to a rejection of organized religion in atheism. This transformation may have occurred in his university years, as a varied program of study, including German, philosophy, and economics ultimately, indicate a mind in ferment.[3]

Eventually, Knight’s studies culminated in a PhD in Economics at Cornell University, earned by completing a dissertation originally titled Cost, Value, and Profit.[4] This later became the work Risk, Uncertainty, and Profit, a seminal work in the understanding of risk, where Knight argued that risk can be assessed in terms of probable outcomes, while uncertainty defines situation where even probability is unknown. This contribution stands very unique and famous in the economic profession, and justified Knight’s high standing enabling him to move to the prestigious University of Chicago.

At Chicago, Frank Knight worked with Professor Jacob Viner to co-edit the Journal of Political Economy and develop high standards in coursework that made Chicago’s program stand out nationally. Attracting excellent students, Knight contributed to the development of many leading scholars, as well as holding together a faculty, including scholars such as Henry Simons and John Nef, which was composed of varied and sometimes conflicting characters. Knight steadily pursued these disciplines, and his authority in scholarly circles remained strong, as reflected by his appointment as founding member and Vice-President of the Mont Pelerin Society.

While Knight’s written work never reached the heights of influence his PhD dissertation Risk, Uncertainty, and Profit achieved, he remained a very productive and diverse scholar. Through simple textbook-like expositions such as The Economic Organization, technical contributions such as “Cost of Production and Price,” and works of social relevance such as Intelligence and Democratic Action, Knight maintained influence through exposition of pressing issues in the economic field, and demonstrated his intellectual virtuosity.

Within Knight’s writing, several themes and emphases clearly emerge. He was broadly concerned with how to execute social science well, including the limitations and methodology of economics. He advocated a broad view of the social scientist as a scholar informed by history, biology, and mathematics, although taking none to excess or as the predominant investigative avenue. This diversity also led Knight to take and even-handed and critical approach. While he often laid down attacks on the principles or outworking of the economic order of the free market, he was equally unsparing with those who sought to replace it, usually concluding that capitalism was better than a host of unconvincing options.

In such inquiries, he never neglected the importance of ethics and values to the field of social science. Not convinced that man and his nature could be simply understood in terms of his material surroundings or pursuit of physical pleasure, Knight articulated a tentative view of social science that operated in light of received knowledge from centuries before. Unfortunately, Knight embraced some unfortunate conceptions of the Middle Ages as unceasingly violent and oppressive of ideas that led him to reject organized religion, tradition, and Church teaching, failing to recognize the real Christian heritage in the liberalism of the eighteenth and nineteenth centuries.

Nevertheless, Knight was always able to clearly lay out the fundamental roots of the economic order of the free market, and the principles on which economics as a science was based. His ability to see the connections between ideas and elements, such as cost, price, supply, and demand, often come through strongly in his writing. For Knight, the world and the men in it were an interconnected whole, but composed of independent parts. His analysis reflected the diversity of his studies and the humility of his thought. The timeless nature of many of his subjects recommend his works as thoroughly as does his career of scholarly investment.

[1] Frank H. Knight, The Ethics of Competition and Other Essays, (New York: Harper & Brothers, 1936), 347-348.

[2] Ibid, 334-335.

[3] “Life,” Frank Hyneman Knight, New World Encyclopedia, accessed December 14, 2018, http://www.newworldencyclopedia.org/entry/Frank_Hyneman_Knight

[4] “Life,” Frank Hyneman Knight, New World Encyclopedia, accessed December 14, 2018, http://www.newworldencyclopedia.org/entry/Frank_Hyneman_Knight

[5] Frank H. Knight, Intelligence and Democratic Action, (Cambridge: Harvard University Press, 1960), 145.

[6] Frank H. Knight, On the History and Method of Economics, (Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 1956), 253-254.