Engaging today's political economy
with truth and reason

sponsored by

Weekly Sage #19: Irving Fisher

15 Mar 2019

The Weekly Sage hopes to regularly bring brief profiles of key contributors to thought and faith before a Christian audience for historical education and awareness of valuable resources.

Irving Fisher

Irving Fisher (1867 – 1947) was one of the leading American economists of the late 19th and early 20th centuries, a period that saw the profession of economics in the United States rise to the level of global impact it has maintained ever since. Fisher, as an original scholar, familiar with the literature of the field across the world, created and integrated concepts prolifically and excellently as an author. In so doing, he led and inspired a new generation of American thinkers including Frank Knight, James Tobin, and Jacob Viner.

Irving Fisher was born in New York and was raised by a Congregationalist minister as a part of the eastern educational and cultural elite. As the post-Civil War era saw vast expansion and economic growth westward, the Atlantic coast saw the development of excellent national institutions, such as Yale College, where Fisher was admitted, achieving the first PhD in Economics granted there. Fisher continued his studies overseas, as was natural in that time for promising American academics.

After his return to the United States, Fisher began teaching at Yale in 1890 at the age of 33, and would remain there throughout his career, taking up the title of professor emeritus 45 years later in 1935. From 1896 to 1910 he edited the Yale Review, and achieved the presidency of the American Economic Association in 1918. He also co-founded the Econometric Society in 1930, and served as that organization’s first president.

Moreover, Fisher was very active beyond the economic field. His fertile mind ranged from social issues such as vegetarianism and prohibition to practical inventions for filing information. This latter work brought him a significant amount of money, and Fisher’s very successful stock investments in the early 20th century brought him even more prominence and respect as an economic thinker. Despite his Christian upbringing, like many of the intellectuals of his day, Fisher embraced atheism as a matter of personal belief, leading him to embrace a popular Social Darwinism and the corresponding cause of eugenics.

Nevertheless, Fisher’s wide-ranging interests did not prevent or distract him from developing significant and influential work in economics. His books, including prominent works such as The Nature of Capital and Income (1906), The Rate of Interest (1907), The Money Illusion (1928), and Booms and Depressions (1932), as well as the more basic textbook Elementary Principles of Economics (1911).

In these writings, Fisher pioneered an increased use of mathematics, utilizing equations, graphs, and data with greater frequency and reliance than his contemporaries. However, his incorporation of real world situations, business applications, and practical scenarios makes his works remarkably readable and easy to understand. While his mind was uniquely able to understand the theoretical and algebraic, this never drew him too far away from the day-to-day, on the ground realities of economics. Fisher’s excellent understandings of the importance of time, risk management, future expectations, and money are indicative of this tight grasp of the human and concrete elements of the market.

Along these lines, Fisher developed lasting contributions and advances in the economic field. The Fisher equation, PV = MT, a founding element of the quantity theory of money, was developed by him, relating together the concepts of price level, velocity of money, stock of money, and amount of transactions. Additionally, he honed the impact of time on capital valuation and interest rates and pioneered the use of index numbers. His work on the nature of money and its impact on the economy was respected by economists from Ludwig von Mises to Gary Becker.

Fisher’s written tone was also distinctively excellent among the economists I have profiled here on the Weekly Sage. His scientific procedure modelled a patience and deliberateness that provide strong confidence in his audience. Definitions were produced with logic and care throughout his works. His logical focus led to consistent criticisms of double-counting, inconsistency, and impracticability of economic terms and frameworks. Fisher not only wanted to ensure the accuracy of his work, but also its relevance and usefulness for the man on the street.

Nevertheless, despite his brilliance, Fisher made some significantly inaccurate predictions regarding the Great Depression, foreseeing instead a consistently high-level of economic performance in the United State just before and during the crash. Moreover, this led to personal as well as professional disaster, with Fisher losing large sums on the stock market. As a result, his subsequent works on depressions, despite their solid analysis of risky credit extensions, failures of business confidence, faulty over-production theories, and stabilization policy were generally ignored in favour of the work of John Maynard Keynes.

Nevertheless, as with much of Fisher’s writings, the lasting relevance of these works is evident to anyone who reads them in light of the 2008 Great Recession. I was surprised by how much of Fisher’s early 20th century work had already appeared in my undergraduate economic studies. However, I was unfortunately not shocked to read that he could not maintain his faith in the light of the significant scientific accomplishments he achieved with his God-given gifts. While the modern record of human sages is replete with example of remarkable work, equal measures of piety are more rarely reconciled with such genius.


[1] Irving Fisher, The Nature of Capital and Income, (New York: The Macmillan Company, 1906), 41.

[2] Ibid, 88 – 89.

[3] Irving Fisher, The Money Illusion, (New York: Adelphi Company, 1928), 60-61.

[4] Irving Fisher, Booms and Depressions: Some First Principles, (London: George Allen & Unwin, 1933), 57.